Free market capitalism
has been the single most important factor in reducing wide-spread poverty and
deprivation across the globe. Unfortunately, neither its detractors (not
surprisingly) nor many of its supporters (disappointingly) fully understand how free market
capitalism works. This inclines many of them to want to use government to
either “fix” it, or to “help” it. Rarely is either accomplished.
In an effort to more
clearly explain how free markets work, I’d like to correct some rather common
misconceptions I see or hear regularly. First, and perhaps most importantly,
supporting free market capitalism is not the same as being anti-government. In
order for free markets to function properly, a government must perform some
basic functions very well. Chief among these functions is having a system in
place that clearly identifies and supports property rights. Capitalism depends
on the ability of individuals to own, improve, and sell property. But only
governments can create the legal framework for property rights that can be
enforced throughout society. There can be no free markets in governments that
cannot give protection to individual property rights.
In addition,
governments must also be able to enforce contracts between individuals and
corporations.
The enforcement of contracts allows a multitude of very positive
transactions to occur that otherwise would not. These transactions increase the
overall welfare of society. Therefore, having a legal system in place that can
enforce agreements between private parties is another essential government
function necessary for free markets to exist and function properly,
Besides these two
fundamental functions of government, free market capitalism also benefits when
the government creates certain health and safety regulations as well as
certain anti-trust and fraud penalties. And while there is room for
disagreement as to what specific regulations can or should be imposed, it is
clear that free markets can benefit from certain governmental regulations.
So, free-market
capitalism is not anti-government. Nor is it pro-“Big Business.” Adams Smith,
in his seminal work, The Wealth of
Nations, pointed out that business owners (especially those of very large
concerns) were as likely to try to impede free markets as to foster them. This
is because free markets are ruthless in their operations. They do not play
favorites. Established businesses will often try to convince governments to
enact various regulations not for “health and safety” purposes, but in order to
limit the amount of competition they face. One of the roles of legislators,
then, according to Smith, was to protect free markets from the inevitable
efforts of the leading “capitalists” to distort markets in favor of their
particular business and at the expense of the overall society.
Another interesting
misconception I often come across is that capitalism creates poverty – as if
poverty did not exist prior to the emergence of capitalism as an economic
system. In one sense this is true. “Poverty” as we understand it, certainly did
not exist in the centuries before capitalism. What did exist was massive
deprivation and destitution. As Nobel Prize-winning Economist Milton Friedman
pointed out, it was only through the emergence of capitalism that large numbers
of people were able to emerge out of subsistence living and begin to see real
improvement in their living standards.
Corresponding to this
misconception is another – that capitalism creates “income inequality.” Again,
to believe this one has to ignore all of the recorded history in which wealth
inequality existed prior to capitalism. In fact, capitalism introduced a major
innovation that, while it doesn’t eliminate wealth inequality, helps to
ameliorate it. That is income mobility. In free market capitalism, as opposed
to any other economic system that has existed, individuals are not confined to
their socio-economic status permanently. Through creativity, industry, perseverance,
or even plain luck, they can improve their situation. Equally important, those
who start off at the top can also lose their position – again free market
capitalism plays no favorites.
There is also a
tremendous amount of confusion about what free markets can and cannot
accomplish. Free markets are extremely good at allocating scarce resources that
have alternative uses, as economist and author Dr. Thomas Sowell has noted.
They are successful at this because of a ruthless efficiency in transmitting
information among the millions of buyers and sellers within the market. This
information, communicated through prices, regulates the supply and demand of
the various goods and services within society. There has not been system
devised that can perform this function as efficiently as market capitalism.
However, markets have
trouble with certain goods or services. Often referred to as “common” goods,can be helpful by creating public policies that require the parties
to the transaction to “internalize” the cost of it to third parties.
these are functions that are necessary within a society that markets generally
cannot provide. Usually because there is no way to ascribe property rights to
the service. Examples would include public safety, national defense, public
assistance, and certain environmental problems. These are where governments must
step in and generally provide the good or service. Markets also have
trouble with externalities. That is, incorporating the costs of a transaction
that impacts third parties (pollution, second-had smoking, etc. are good
examples of this). This is where government action
It is important to
understand, however, that government’s ability to effectively correct “market
failures” is also limited. Primarily by a deficiency in the information needed
to be as effective as necessary. Public policies to impact economic performance
are almost always after-the fact. Economist Robert Guell identifies three
important constraints on effective government intervention in market activity.
First is the “recognition
lag.” This is the amount of time it takes government officials to recognize
there is a problem that may need government action. For example, the official
definition of a “recession” is two consecutive quarters of negative economic
growth. This means that half a year must pass before policymakers can even be
sure there is a problem. This is followed by “administrative lag” which is the
time it takes policymakers to actually devise a “solution” to the problem (which can also take months).
Finally, there is the “operational lag” which is the amount of time it takes (often several more months) for the agreed upon solution to be implemented.
As Guell points out,
the economy is not standing still waiting on policymakers to identify, create,
and implement their solution. And in many cases, by the time the solution
reaches its implementation phase, the problem has been corrected already. The
information conveyed through markets is done so much more efficiently and with
much fewer obstacles than information conveyed through government
bureaucracies.
While free markets
cannot, by themselves, solve a variety of social problems such as racism,
sexism, drug addiction, etc., they can help reduce these. By forcing business
owners and managers to choose between their bigotry and hiring the most
productive employees, or serving the most customers, free markets can have a
positive impact. And to the extent that they bring people of diverse
backgrounds together to be equal participants within the market, further
improvement in these areas can be found. However, it must be acknowledged that
there is nothing inherent in free markets that will force bigots to reform.
However, the central
insight of Smith’s exposition of capitalism was its benefit to society. Free
market capitalism isn’t good because it allows a few people to get extremely
rich, or that it allows companies to hire people, or that it allows new
businesses to grow and develop. It is good because it is the best economic
arrangement for increasing the living standard of the entire society. If you
doubt this, simply as yourself this question, in which of the following years
would I rather be poor: 2015, 1915,
1815, 1715, 1315, or 1015? When you think about it, it’s a pretty easy question
to answer – especially if you live in a free-market, capitalist-based economy.
Whether you are
evaluating the living standards of the poor, the amount of wealth inequality
within
various societies over these time periods, or the ability of those who
are most poor to rise out of it, 2015 by far, offers the most hope for the
poor. And in countries that are based on some version of free-market
capitalism, the poor live in far better conditions and have greater opportunity
for social mobility than their counterparts living under other economic systems
– regardless of the year.
In short, free-market
capitalism offers the greatest opportunity for continuing to increase living
standards, offering social mobility to those at all income levels, and spurring
innovation. However, free markets, rather than being opposed to government,
actually rely on governments to perform certain important functions. While they
can help alleviate certain social problems, they are not a panacea for all
social ills. Other institutions, both governmental and non-governmental, are
needed to successfully address these problems.